@Noahpinion can the @LivingWageNZ model close the 30% wage gap with Australia? @arindube

Noah Smith overnight argued that increasing the minimum wage to $15 an hour in the USA will induce innovation that will, in time, mitigate much of the costs of the minimum wage increase to employers:

So minimum-wage laws, by forcing us to abandon low-skilled labour, might actually increase technological innovation. Some people even speculate that this effect might have started the Industrial Revolution itself! Economic historian Robert Allen has argued that the Industrial Revolution began in Europe, rather than in China, because European employers were forced to pay more for labour. Since labour was more expensive, companies invested in technology, which then raised productivity so much that it boosted wages even higher, forcing companies to invest more in technology, even as their increased incomes allowed them to make those investments. A 1987 theory by growth economics pioneer Paul Romer operated on a similar principle — expensive labour causes an upward spiral of technological improvement. 

Smith is confusing induced innovation with standard substitution effects and offsetting behaviour. When you make something more expensive, buyers look for cheaper alternatives including technologies that were previously unprofitable to employ.

Up until the minimum wage increase, these labour saving technologies were not profitable investments because the best available choice was still lawful to employ, which was low skilled labour. A minimum wage increase makes it unlawful to employ the best available alternative. As Modeled Behaviour explains better than me:

If throwing the costly challenges of artificially expensive Labor at businesses drives economic growth, then perhaps we should have an Office of Government Hurdles that is designed to generate arbitrary restrictions for businesses. After all, if this innovation is a driver of economic growth it should have value by itself and not simply as a by-product of some other regulatory goal, e.g. keeping out immigrants or raising wages. Consider a law that banned bending over in the workplace. Is there any doubt that this would spur innovative products that aided in grabbing without bending? Or consider a law that mandated everyone work from home. This would spur massive investment in broadband and telecommunications. But there is no doubt we would be poorer from both of these regulations.

One of the reasons demand curves slope downwards is as the price of the good increases, buyers have other options so they stop buying and pursue these other options which include innovation.

Smith also falls for the standard labour market policy response in a crisis, which is to send them on a course:

And as workers raise their own skill levels, that new technology would raise their wages as well. The entire economy, including any workers who temporarily lost their low-wage jobs, would benefit in the long run. Of course, this theory is fairly speculative — theories that play out over years or decades are hard to test with real-world data. But it’s a potential benefit of the minimum wage that is worth thinking about.

Whenever there is a crisis in the labour market, the standard policy response is send them on a course. That makes you look like you care and by the time they graduate, the problem might have fixed itself. I encountered this policy response to labour market crises to repeat itself over and over again while working in the bureaucracy.

Clever geeks such as yourself sitting at your desk as a policy analysis, public intellectual, politician, activist or minister did well at university. University graduates succumb to the fatal conceit when they assume others will as well, including those who have neither the ability or aptitude to succeed in education.

Educational romanticism will not solve the disemployment problems of a minimum wage increase. People don’t go on from high school to higher education for a range of reasons that include a lack of motivation to study or a simple lack of ability no matter how hard they try.

Charles Murray believes many students make poor investments by going to college, in part, because many don’t complete their degrees:

…even though college has been dumbed down, it is still too intellectually demanding for a large majority of students, in an age when about 50 per cent of all high school graduates are heading to four-year colleges the next fall. The result is lots of failure. Of those who entered a four-year college in 1995, only 58 per cent had gotten their BA five academic years later

Murray does not want to abandon these teenagers:

…Too few counsellors tell work-bound high-school students how much money crane operators or master stonemasons make (a lot). Too few tell them about the well-paying technical specialties that are being produced by a changing job market. Too few assess the non-academic abilities of work-bound students and direct them toward occupations in which they can reasonably expect to succeed. Worst of all: As these students approach the age at which they can legally drop out of school, they are urged to take more courses in mathematics, literature, history and science so that they can pursue the college fantasy. Is it any wonder that so many of them drop out?

Charles Murray is frank about educational romanticism. Half the population is of below average IQ. That is before considering the necessary personality traits to be a successful student. Asking people without the necessary IQ and personality traits to waste their time with up skilling insults them.

Carrying that send them on a course educational romanticism over to the minimum wage and living wage debates is to use the low skilled as lab rats in the social experiments that are bound to fail as they failed in the past.

One of the purposes of applied price theory, the study of economic history and even labour econometrics is to spare us policy experiments we already know will not turn out well.

We do know what will happen if the minimum wage is raised to $15 per hour. Some people will lose their jobs. More importantly, there is a reduced incentive for the low paid to invest in skills to improve their earning power because the minimum wage is already delivered that assuming they still have a job. Human capital effects of minimum wage increases is under discussed.

As for investing in up skilling, active labour market programs that invest heavily in upskilling the unemployed have a dreadful record. This dreadful record is when there are subsidies direct to the unemployed going on prearranged courses focused on work skills. We’re not talking about indirect incentives such as raising the minimum wage and hoping for the best regarding their upskilling both on the job or while on the unemployment benefit.

Back to Noah Smith. He admits that increases in the minimum wage reduce employment. He tries to ride out on the conclusion that that increase in unemployment after a small minimum wage increase isn’t much.

Obviously the teenagers and adults thrown onto the scrapheap of society by the increased minimum wage don’t count in the brutal utilitarian calculus employed by Noah Smith and other champions of the low paid.

Smith is now trying to fortify his argument by arguing that minimum wage activists have spotted an untapped innovation right under the noses of entrepreneurs who profit from exploiting gaps in the market faster than the rest. Bureaucrats and politicians notice these gaps in the market before those who gain from superior entrepreneur alertness to hitherto untapped opportunities for profit do so and instead leave that money on the table.

What is even richer in this induced innovation hypothesis of Noah Smith and others is many of these minimum wage workers are in the services sector. Services suffer from Baumol’s disease: the limited ability to innovate in labour-intensive areas.

The optimal timing of innovation spawned a vast literature. So has offsetting behaviour to regulation. The former innovation is welfare enhancing. The latter is mitigation of the dead weight social losses of regulation.

What and where to innovate is a process of market discovery. The life cycle of many industries starts with a burst of new entrants with similar products and production processes. These new or upgraded products and the different ways of making them often use ideas that cross-fertilise.

In time, there is an industry shakeout where a few leapfrog the rest with cost savings and design breakthroughs to yield the mature product (Boldrin and Levine 2008, 2013). Fast-seconds and practical minded latecomers often imitate and successfully commercialise ideas seeded by the market pioneers using prior ideas as their base.

This entire dynamic market process of competitive selection, competition as a discovery procedure, trial and error and leapfrogging is distorted if one or more of the contending entrepreneurs as their hand forced by regulation on labour imports rather than because of competitive merits. The government cannot enable this process because neither the outcome nor even the direction of the competitive struggle for survival is known in advance. To quote Thomas Babington (1830):

The maxim, that governments ought to train the people in the way in which they should go, sounds well. But is there any reason for believing that a government is more likely to lead the people in the right way than the people to fall into the right way of themselves?

The firms that survive and grow in competition with rival ways of doing business are the more efficient simply because they survived. What will survive in market competition will not be known in advance to politicians and activists when they decide to make one specific input more expensive. The results of the competitive market process that weeds out the less efficient firm are known at the end of this long race, not at the start.

Knowing that innovation is induced by changing relative prices and wages doesn’t help wise bureaucrats and farsighted politician know which one of those relative prices or wages will be decisive in determining the direction of innovation. As Alfred Marshall explains in The Social Possibilities of Economic Chivalry (1907):

A Government could print a good edition of Shakespeare’s works, but it could not get them written… I am only urging that every new extension of Governmental work in branches of production which need ceaseless creation and initiative is to be regarded as prima facie anti-social, because it retards the growth of that knowledge and those ideas which are incomparably the most important form of collective wealth.

What is not explored adequately in this debate by either Noah Smith or the New Zealand Living Wage Movement is why limit the efficiency wage and induced innovation hypotheses to low skilled workers.

Why not increase the wages of all workers by 20-30%? There will not be a large disemployment effect and the induced innovation will mitigate the costs, if Noah Smith and his efficiency wage and induced innovation hypotheses are to be believed.

30% would be a good number for increasing all New Zealand wages was that is about the wage gap with Australia. Let’s go for broke. What’s the risk other than massive unemployment and economic chaos?

The living wage sought in New Zealand and the fight for $15 campaign in the USA presuppose massive offsetting labour productivity gains. A doubling in labour productivity overnight in low-paid service and other jobs or at least within a few years because of higher work morale.

The labour productivity increase required to offset even some of the costs of the double-digit living wage increases proposed at home and abroad are large, very large:

Looking first at the 2016 position, the proposed wage floor increase would require productivity growth of around 11% between 2015 and 2016. By 2020, the cumulative productivity gains from 2015 would need to rise above 37%, implying an average annual increase of 6.6%… the pace of productivity growth implied by our thought exercise is unprecedented: the annual average increase during the economic growth years of 1991-2008 was 2.2%. That points to two conclusions. First, firms are likely to need support in meeting the productivity challenge. And second, any productivity plan should look beyond the obvious forms of high-tech wizardry in high value-added sectors to encompass new forms of organisational approaches and business models in our most labour-absorbing industries.

What is missing in most discussions of the efficiency wage hypothesis and the latest discussion of induced innovation and wage increases is, as the Washington Centre for Equitable Growth notes is the upper limit on the wage increase that carries only minimal disemployment risks:

Many activists and policymakers across the country are vigorously pushing for an increase in the minimum wage at the federal, state, and local levels. Of course, while many people agree that the minimum wage needs to be higher, that still leaves the question of how high it should be… The trouble, however, is taking that research and applying it to potential minimum wage increases that would be outside the range of previous hikes. For example, raising the current federal minimum wage from $7.25 to $15—more than doubling it—would be significantly larger than prior increases.

That upper bound discussion is a small hole in their arguments compared to their failure to advocate massive efficiency wage increases and massive induced innovation wage increases across the entire economy. Why is the efficiency wage and induced innovation hypotheses only extended to the low paid? Why not hire wages for everyone?

One of the reasons for the high labour productivity in Western Europe is their minimum wages, employment protection laws and high taxes made it unprofitable to employee low skilled service workers.

European consumers innovated in the face of these high costs of taxes and regulation by doing for themselves what Americans buy on the market be it anything from takeaways to home help. That is well known as Richard Rogerson explains:

The empirical work establishes two results. First, hours worked in Europe decline by almost 45 percent compared to the United States over this period [from 1956 to 2003]. Second, this decline is almost entirely accounted for by the fact that Europe develops a much smaller market service sector than the United States… relative increases in taxes and technological catch-up can account for most of the differences between the European and American time allocations over this period.

The phenomena that developed in Europe as the result of the additional costs of taxes and labour market regulation is known as Eurosclerosis, not a productivity breakout through efficiency wages and induced innovation.

2 Comments (+add yours?)

  1. Trackback: @geoffsimmonz @suemoroney @janlogie minimum wage increases gender gap | Utopia - you are standing in it!
  2. Jace Wright, The Ignorant Scholar
    Dec 11, 2015 @ 13:43:08

    When does the wage stop? what principle do you use to judge when it is too much? $100? $200? $1,000,000,000? Is it just enough to live on? Living costs vary greatly, some people can go weeks without eating. Is it just enough to live comfortably? How do you judge “comfortably”? If you want better wages, boycott low-wage industries, and instead work for ones that pay livable wages.

    Like

    Reply

Leave a comment

This site uses Akismet to reduce spam. Learn how your comment data is processed.

Down to Earth Kiwi

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

NoTricksZone

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

Homepaddock

A rural perspective with a blue tint by Ele Ludemann

Kiwiblog

DPF's Kiwiblog - Fomenting Happy Mischief since 2003

thewartimekitchen.com

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

The Dangerous Economist

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

Watts Up With That?

The world's most viewed site on global warming and climate change

Moneyness

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

The Logical Place

Tim Harding's writings on rationality, informal logic and skepticism

Doc's Books

A window into Doc Freiberger's library

The Risk-Monger

Let's examine hard decisions!

Uneasy Money

Commentary on monetary policy in the spirit of R. G. Hawtrey

Bassett, Brash & Hide

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

Barrie Saunders

Thoughts on public policy and the media

Liberty Scott

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

Vincent Geloso

Econ Prof at George Mason University, Economic Historian, Québécois

Point of Order

Politics and the economy

James Bowden's Blog

A blog (primarily) on Canadian and Commonwealth political history and institutions

Science Matters

Reading between the lines, and underneath the hype.

Peter Winsley

Economics, and such stuff as dreams are made on

A Venerable Puzzle

"The British constitution has always been puzzling, and always will be." --Queen Elizabeth II

Real Time with Bill Maher Blog

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

No Minister

Laughing at Our Elites

The Antiplanner

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

Bet On It

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

Anti-Dismal

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

Bowalley Road

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

History of Sorts

WORLD WAR II, MUSIC, HISTORY, HOLOCAUST

Tudor Chronicles

News, reviews and talk all about the Tudors

Roger Pielke Jr.

Undisciplined scholar, recovering academic

Offsetting Behaviour

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

JONATHAN TURLEY

Res ipsa loquitur - The thing itself speaks

Conversable Economist

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

The Victorian Commons

Researching the House of Commons, 1832-1868

Coyote Blog

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

The History of Parliament

Blogging on parliament, politics and people, from the History of Parliament

Books & Boots

Reflections on books and art

Legal History Miscellany

Posts on the History of Law, Crime, and Justice

Sex, Drugs and Economics

Celebrating humanity's flourishing through the spread of capitalism and the rule of law

Media Myth Alert

Calling out media myths

European Royal History

Exploring the Monarchs of Europe

Tallbloke's Talkshop

Cutting edge science you can dice with

Marginal REVOLUTION

Small Steps Toward A Much Better World

NOT A LOT OF PEOPLE KNOW THAT

“We do not believe any group of men adequate enough or wise enough to operate without scrutiny or without criticism. We know that the only way to avoid error is to detect it, that the only way to detect it is to be free to inquire. We know that in secrecy error undetected will flourish and subvert”. - J Robert Oppenheimer.

STOP THESE THINGS

The truth about the great wind power fraud - we're not here to debate the wind industry, we're here to destroy it.

Trust, yet verify

Searching for the missing pieces of climate change communication